ECONOMIC SYSTEMIslamic Finance

The Nature of Paper Money – Some history and observations, by A.L.M. Abdul Gafoor – Appropriate Technology Foundation Groningen, The Netherlands

Gold and money
From time immemorial gold was money.  Valuable goods were priced in terms of gold: this product is worth so many ounces of gold.  But assessing the fineness of the metal and weighing it each time a transaction took place was a tedious and wasteful exercise.  This led to the invention of the gold coin.  Mints which produced the coins certified to its fineness and weight, and its accuracy was attested to in the name of the ruling monarch.  This made the process of counting and exchanging easier.  The values stamped on the coins were generally taken at face value, but their accuracy could be easily ascertained.  Therefore a gold coin minted anywhere and issued in the name of any king was acceptable anywhere in the world, for it had an intrinsic value as well.  It was universally accepted that gold was money and gold coins were currency.  Silver and copper were also similarly used.
The reputation of a coin depended on the integrity of the issuing monarch and the stability of his reign.  Sometimes people chipped away a tiny piece of the coin and passed it off for the face value.  Sometimes the mints themselves used less fine material or less weight – often on the orders of the king – but stamped it otherwise.  Yet verification of the true value was easy and the debased coins quickly acquired the reputation they deserved.  Each country determined the size, shape and name of its own coin, but the real worth of the currency depended on the actual gold content of the coin.  This state of affairs continued till the invention of the paper currency.

Paper currency and the gold standard
Paper currency began its existence in Europe when the goldsmith issued a receipt for the gold coins deposited with him by a merchant and this receipt began to be accepted by other merchants in the city as good as the coins themselves.  For the merchants it eliminated the risk and trouble of carrying large amounts of coins.
The goldsmith’s reputation and trustworthiness played a part in this, and he took it a step further and issued his own “I-owe-you” notes (of course for a price) which acquired the same credibility among the merchants as his deposit receipts.  When the goldsmith and moneylender became a bank, the bank issued bank notes, which became a convenient alternative form of currency and acquired credibility among the general populace as well.  Each bank issued its own notes, and its popularity depended on the bank’s reputation.  But a bank’s reputation did not extend much beyond its own city and its environs.  So notes of several banks came into circulation.
Multiplicity of banks, bank failures, and fraud compelled the government to step in and to declare itself the sole authority to issue currency notes.  This was the beginning the national paper currency and it began in England in the eighteenth century.  Gold was still money, but the paper represented money, and the paper currency was eventually made legal tender by law.  Since the law held within the country, people held less and less gold coins in their hands for use in domestic transactions.  They used the paper proxy, but this paper currency was guaranteed (by the crown/government/central bank) to be equivalent to a certain fixed weight of gold, and it could be converted into that fixed weight of gold (or silver) anytime at designated outlets.
For international transactions, however, gold bullion or gold coins (readily exchanged for the paper currency) were used.  And the perception that the paper was as good as gold got ingrained into the minds of people.  Over time, the long-standing British practice (since 1717), the strength of her economy, and the vastness of her colonial rule augmented this mind-set throughout a good part of the world.
By the end of the Napoleonic Wars (1815), many currencies of the world were based on either gold or silver.  By the end of the nineteenth century, gold replaced silver as the basis of monetary arrangements in practically all of the major trading nations.  The readily convertible, fixed-rate gold-currency relationship, along with the private citizen’s right to freely hold, export and import gold, came to be known as the gold standard.  Between 1880 and 1914, the gold standard prevailed on a global scale, and gave the impression that international gold standard was the normal state of affairs.  The benefits included price and exchange-rate stability, which helped to conduct local and international trade and investment with minimum risk of capital loss.  This further strengthened the trust in the paper currency and the gold standard.
The metal content of the previous era gave the coins a readily verifiable amount of intrinsic value.  The paper currency, however, was in fact only an “I-owe-you” promissory note that depended for its validity entirely on the issuing bank’s promise to abide by the gold standard.  But, even this promise was not always truly adhered to; there were devaluations, restrictions and suspensions.  For example, Britain was on a full legal gold standard from 1821 and on a de facto standard from 1717.  But during the Napoleonic Wars, Britain experienced severe inflation which necessitated the suspension of convertibility.  To prevent a recurrence of inflation, a law of 1819 required the Bank of England to make its notes redeemable in gold at the market price prevailing in May 1821 [as opposed to the fixed official rate].
The United States broke with gold in 1933.  In March 1933 President Roosevelt restricted foreign-exchange dealings and gold and currency movements, and in April he issued an executive order requiring individuals to deliver their gold coin, bullion and gold certificates to Federal Reserve Banks.  By setting progressively higher dollar prices for gold, the Administration engineered a series of devaluations, leaving the dollar with 59 percent of its former gold content. By 1936, when France and other countries of the Gold Bloc had suspended convertibility, only the US maintained a link between domestic currency and gold.  But with international gold flows restricted and the US$35 gold price a matter of convenience rather than law, American monetary arrangements embodied none of the basic elements of the gold standard.
Things changed drastically between the two World Wars, especially since the depression of the thirties.  By 1936 nearly all countries had broken the link between gold and currency, all currencies were on a free-float, the exchange-rate stability was broken, and the free flow of gold between countries was restricted or prohibited – the basic characteristics of the gold standard have been taken away.  Consequently, international trade and balance-of-payments experienced unprecedented difficulties.  This led to some serious concerns and to the Bretton Woods Conference, held in the US towards the end of the War.
The Bretton Woods Agreement
In 1944, the Bretton Woods Agreement was negotiated and in 1945, forty countries – that is, practically all the countries then in existence – signed the Agreement.
Its main sponsors were the United Kingdom and the United States.  One of the main purposes was to bring about exchange rate stability in order to help world trade.  This was to be achieved by fixing the value of the US dollar as equivalent to a certain weight of gold and then fixing the values of all other currencies of the world in terms of the US dollar.  Thus every currency was theoretically equivalent to a certain weight of gold.  So gold provided the basic unit for all currencies, and the stability of the exchange-rate was to emanate from this basic unity.  This meant that every product anywhere in the world had a unique price in terms of gold, though it may be quoted differently in different national currencies.
Previous to this each currency  was directly anchored to gold – every currency was equivalent to a certain weight of gold – but now only the US dollar was directly anchored to gold.  And all other currencies only through the US dollar.  It was sometimes called the gold-dollar standard.  This was the second major shift in the gold-currency relationship.
Under the Bretton Woods Agreement, the US dollar was fixed as equivalent to 1/35 fine ounces of gold (i.e. one ounce of gold was set equivalent to 35 US dollars) and the US Government guaranteed to maintain this ratio, and to exchange every US dollar presented to it (at the “gold window”) into the equivalent weight of gold at anytime.  All other countries promised to peg their own currencies at a fixed rate to the dollar.  The International Monetary Fund was established to maintain this regime.  From now on no national currency could be presented to the issuing central bank for conversion into gold.  While gold was still held as reserve, the US dollar became the major reserve currency at the central banks, and almost all foreign exchange dealings took place through the US dollar.  Only central banks (and some industrial users of gold) could present their US dollar holdings at the US “gold window” for exchange into gold.
But the US Government financed its growing budget deficits by printing dollars, without regard to its gold reserves (especially in the 1960’s), and began to use exchange controls and moral suasion to discourage central-bank conversion of American financial assets into gold.  By the end of 1970, official US dollar claims of foreigners had mounted to more than twice the US gold reserves.  Fearing an imminent run on her gold reserves, the US Government, suddenly on Sunday 15 August 1971, closed its “gold window”, severed the US dollar’s link with gold, and unilaterally broke its promise under the Bretton Woods Agreement.  Evidently, all other signatories to the Agreement put together could not have the Agreement enforced.  Now the US dollar floated freely, and all other currencies floated even more freely.  This was the third major shift in the in the gold-currency relationship, and a final break at that.
Modern currencies
The currency is still a promissory note, but all issuing authorities have absolved themselves of any obligation (legal or otherwise) of redeeming it in gold (or any other thing of value), nor even in any other currency.  Now it is the citizen’s expectation that other citizens will honour the printed paper he holds in his hands that keeps the currency afloat.  The moment one citizen refuses to honour the promise that nobody promised anybody, it will trigger a complete collapse of the currency system.  But that right of refusal is denied by law, because it is designated as “legal tender”.  Money has become an illusion – a very rare kind of illusion that is imposed, legalized and enforced.
In 2002, Europe replaced one illusion with another illusion – the currencies of 12 European nations were replaced with a single currency, the Euro.  Literally overnight, 31 December 2001 / 1 January 2002, one of the world’s most valued “hard currency” – the German Mark – along with its counterparts from France, the Netherlands, Belgium, Italy and others, became mere used paper worth nothing, and a mere printed paper became “legal tender”.  It was done “legally” and “democratically”.  The world watched on its television screens truck-loads of the old currencies being shredded and made into pulp, to be turned later into toilet paper!  The coins were also melted for re-use, but their metallic value remained intact.
The US dollar is officially designated as “Federal Reserve Note” and has printed on it (1985 series) the name of the country (The United States of America), name of the currency (Dollar), denomination (one, ten, etc), a serial number, a statement (This note is legal tender for all debts, public and private), and the signatures of the Treasurer of the United States and the Secretary of State.  The Canadian dollar is issued in the name of the Bank of Canada, signed in Ottawa by the Governor and Deputy Governor of the Bank of Canada, and has the statement, “This note is legal tender” (1973).

The British Pound is issued in the name of the Bank of England, signed in London by the Chief Cashier “for the Governor and Company of the Bank of England” and carries the promise, “I promise to pay the bearer on demand a sum of … pounds”.  But what is a “pound”?  Where is it defined, and how?  Or, is it a pound of gold, copper, paper or meat?  Whatever it is, will the BoE keep the promise and hand it to me in exchange for their note in my hands?

The Indian Rupee is issued by the Reserve Bank of India, signed by the Governor, guaranteed by the Central Government, and carries the promise, “I promise to pay the bearer the sum of … rupees”.  What is a rupee?  Another kind of “circular argument”? Most currency notes have similar formulations, have intricate designs and often carry the portrait of the present head of government or an important personality or symbol of the nation.
But the newest of all currencies – the Euro – has the most economical formulation. It has a serial number, denomination, a copyright line, “© BCE ECB EZB EKT EKP 2002”, and nothing else!  There is apparently a signature, but whose and on whose behalf?  What is this intricately designed piece of modern art, what does it signify, and what is it to be used for?  It does not even promise to be legal tender!

Price of gold
From 1945 to 1971, every currency had a fixed relationship to the US dollar and the US dollar, in turn, to gold at the rate of 35 dollars per ounce of fine gold.  Consequently, every product anywhere in the world had a unique ultimate price in terms gold.  But gold itself did not have a price in any currency.  For gold was money, currency.  It was measured by weight.  An ounce of gold was an ounce of gold; any number of units of gold was that number of units of gold.  35 US dollars was equivalent to one ounce of gold, not that the price of gold was 35 US dollars.
But gold was no longer legal tender (currency), the dollar was.  No gold coins were minted anymore.  If you are in the US and your tax bill was 350 dollars, you could not pay 10 ounces of gold at the counters of the tax department; you have to pay in dollar bills.  Neither was gold acceptable at the supermarket cash counter for the goods in your trolley.  But you could still (in theory) exchange gold for US dollar and US dollar for gold at the US “gold window”, at the fixed rate of 35 dollars per ounce of gold.  However, since no one any longer transacted business in terms of gold and .everyone used the dollar, because it was the only legal tender, gold can be obtained commercially only by paying for it in dollars.  This amount of dollars paid per ounce of gold became the price of gold.  Even though its official rate was still 35 dollars per ounce, for ordinary purposes, gold was bought and sold at commercial outlets, and on account of their expenses such as handling charges, trading costs and business profit, it was sold at a different “price”.
Gold has now acquired a price and has become just another commodity.  People got used to thinking of it as a commodity, and it had a price just like any other commodity.  Yet, it did not vary much from the official rate The real break came in 1971, when the official rate was ended with the stroke of a pen.  From then on there was no holding back.  Now we talk about the price of gold!  Currently (January 2008), it is over 900 US dollars per ounce.
Was it gold going up in price or the dollar going down in value?  This question is rarely asked.  The price goes up because of high demand for gold (or its short supply), or is it the currency depreciating?  Is anybody in control?  Obviously not any government or central bank; neither the IMF.  If it is laissez-faire, then freedom from government control for whose benefit?

A simile
The above situation can be expressed by a simile.  Suppose we are at a railway station, and there is a train standing at the station.  Suppose there are two observers, P and T, one on the platform (P) and the other on the train (T).  Since the train is not moving, whether one stands on the platform or sits in the train he is at rest.  Now, suppose there is a car moving on a road parallel to the track.  Whether you measure its speed from the platform or from the train, the car will have the same speed.  If P and T made the observations, both their observations of speed of the car will be identical, because they are both fixed relative to the ground.  Now, suppose P also got into the train and both made their separate observations.  Their measurements will still be identical – whether they stood on the platform or sat in the train their observations showed the same results.  Seeing this, say, they decide to sit together in the train and make their observations.
Now, suppose, unnoticed by our observers, a driver got into the train and moved it. What will happen to the measurements of our observers?  Their observations of the speed of the car moving along the road will be identical, and they will believe that it was the true speed.  But, is it?  It will not tally with the observations of another observer on the ground or on the platform.  The difference will be the speed of the train.  P and T may still argue that their observations gave the true speed of the car; they might even genuinely believe that the station was suddenly moving away from them!  If there was no one on the platform and all the people were on the train, everyone will believe so too.  The station and the platform are moving away from us! Our saying that the price of gold is going up is exactly the same. When the driver reverses the train, the station and the platform will move towards us.  Gold price is going down!  The earlier we get off the train and get out of this illusion the better.
But somehow people seem to have been mesmerized into forgetting that standing on the ground is the normal state of affairs, when you have the ability to move whichever way you like and at whatever speed you wish, and that when you are sitting in a moving train with all the doors locked it is the driver who decides the speed and direction of your movement.

Currency and price
Currency is expected to serve three basic purposes: unit of account, medium of exchange, and store of value.  The unit of account function allowed every product to be priced in terms of the currency.  This was an important step in the development of commerce.  Now every product can be given a unique price and, since the currency unit was common to the whole country, the price of any given product could be compared across the country or the worth of any product could be compared with that of any other.  The medium of exchange function allowed products to be easily bought and sold for money at competitively determined prices, rather than bartered with the attendant cumbersome search for matching products.
The store of value function enabled the money earned by selling a product or service to be kept in store until another product or service was actually needed.  This also enabled delayed payment for goods and services and the taking and returning of loans with a time delay, without any loss to either party.  Every product has a price in terms of the currency of the country.  This chair is 5 dollars, this book is10 riyals, this shirt is 15 rupees, etc.  What is the price of currency?  What is the price of a dollar, a riyal, a rupee?  It is one dollar, one riyal, one rupee.  The difference is: the price of a chair may vary from day to day, depending on supply and demand, but the price of one dollar remains one dollar at all times.  So is the value of every currency, in its own terms.
Price change – inflation or deflation – affects the price of products, but it has no effect on the value of currency, because it is measured in its own units.  Why?  That is how we have defined money.  One dollar (riyal or rupee) is always one dollar (riyal or rupee); that is our common unit in which we have decided to measure all our prices.
It may look absurd, but consider the following scenario.  Say, the price of the chair went up from 5 dollars to 10 dollars.  Now, suppose we decided to make the chair our currency.  Then, we will have a price for the dollar in terms of chairs!  And, the price of the dollar in the above scenario would be 1/5 of a chair!   Consequently, when the price changed, instead of the chair going up in price it would be the dollar going down in price – the value of dollar goes down from 1/5 of a chair to 1/10 of a chair, from 0.20 ch to 0.10 ch.
Currency – dollar or chair – so long as we unambiguously define and identify it and agree on what constitutes one unit of it, will serve the purposes of the unit of account and medium of exchange.  Present-day paper currencies, whatever their names, serve these purposes very well.  There is no dispute over it.  So the paper currency is still useful, viable, valuable and indispensable.

Inflation and currency depreciation
However, it is in its third function – that of store of value – that modern paper currency fails miserably.  It does not keep its value from year to year, sometimes even from month to month.  The same dollar (or any other currency) that bought a loaf of bread last year does not buy a similar loaf of bread this year.  We can say the dollar has depreciated in value.  But others would say the price has increased (due to inflation).  Since there are tools to measure inflation (e.g. the consumer price index), and none to measure currency depreciation (depreciation against what?), our position has no legs to stand on.
Inflation was defined as positive change in price, and this change was assumed to be brought about by supply/demand interaction.  A negative change was called deflation.  When inflation/deflation was defined, money was still anchored to gold, and there was currency stability.  And, prices changed positively and negatively.  But, today’s price change includes currency depreciation (of monetary value) as well.
To illustrate, suppose the price of a loaf of bread was 50 cents last year and has changed to 60 cents this year.  This is a 20 percent price increase which is defined as 20 percent inflation.  This can be expressed as: current price = old price + currency depreciation (i.e. 60 = 50 +10). To put it in another way, one cent which bought 1/50 of a loaf of bread last year buys only 1/60 of it today.  That is why your 50 cents now buys only 50/60 of the loaf and you must pay 10 cents extra to obtain the full loaf.  If we assume the quality and quantity of the bread as well as the demand and supply remained the same, then it must be the currency that has changed its character.  In other words, the currency has depreciated by 1/6 or 16.7 percent.  This requires extra money to be paid for the same bread, and this is reflected in the new price.  We have no tools to measure currency depreciation but have an index to measure the price change. Therefore, we talk about the latter and call it inflation.   Since currency depreciation is the major part of today’s price change, it has become a one-way street – always positive, inflation.  Any deflation – due to excess supply, low demand, or increased efficiency – is masked by currency

depreciation.
Currency depreciation could be brought about in many ways, but the major enduring cause could be traced to deficit financing.  Other sources of currency fluctuation (and depreciation) include government expediency, currency trading raids, bank credit creation, gold price fixing, and interest rate manipulations.  Since the main players in all these actions are a powerful few, currency depreciation is a manipulated affair.  And, since currency depreciation is the major component in the recorded price change, today’s observed inflation has little to do with free-market competition.  The people, in whose name most of today’s governments are run – of the people, for the people, by the people – have no say in the matter, except to bear the consequences.

Interest and inflation
In Christendom, till 1545, usury was prohibited.  In that year the British parliament was persuaded to pass the Usury Law.  This law introduced an innocuous word called interest, and usury was defined as high rate of interest.  Usury was still prohibited, in deference to the Church, but “reasonable” interest was made permissible.  What is reasonable and what is high was to be determined by the Parliament, and in 1545 it was decided to fix it at ten percent per annum.  Eventually interest was accepted in all countries of Europe and the Americas.  Over time the limit ceased to exist and even the word usury went out of use.
Now that interest was legal, money was available only at a price.  Those who had savings and were unwilling to take risks deposited their money in the bank and demanded interest.  The bank, in turn, lent it to those who needed money and charged them at a higher rate.  A good portion of the nation’s savings filled the vaults of the bank and the owners made money out of other peoples’ money.  They grew rich and powerful – sometimes even more powerful than their government.
The law recognizes interest but not inflation.  When currency depreciation was engineered and passed off as inflation the bank got its second chance.  It adjusted its interest rates to accommodate inflation and compensate for value loss of capital.  The new rate was called nominal interest rate and was set equal to the real interest rate plus the inflation rate.  Inflation began to eat into the value of currency, and it ate even while the money was held in one’s own hands.  People panicked and sought to protect their savings.  The bank’s new offer seemed a good option and they went for it.  If you cannot be induced by interest to surrender your wealth to the bank, you will be driven to it through inflation!
More money filled the bank’s vaults and the owners became richer and globally powerful.  That seems to be the end result of moving from gold to paper and dumping the gold standard.  The old owl said, “I used to see you carrying sacks of gold, now you have bundles of paper.  Where has all the gold gone?”
The bank is the stronger party in any lending/borrowing transactions, and it used inflation rate projections too to its advantage.  Savings deposits and loans are by nature future commitments, and forecasts of inflation rates will have a range.  The bank used the lower rate when paying interest to the depositors and the higher rate when charging the borrowers, profiting both ways.  What a bonanza!
Muslim dilemma
The bank’s offer was a good option to those who had no qualms about paying or receiving interest.  But Muslims are prohibited by their religion to deal in interest in any manner.  That lands them in a dilemma.  If they hold their savings or wealth in the form of currency its value is slowly eroded by inflation, and if they go to the bank for protection against it they will be dealing in the prohibited interest.  This is a specifically Muslim problem and therefore they alone have to find a solution.  Others are not so affected by it and therefore cannot be expected to seek one.
A solution may become available if the real interest rate and the inflation rate combined in the nominal rate can be separated from each other.  Here too what needs to be computed is the realised inflation rate and not the speculative one used by the bank.  It is no easy task, but what we are really after is not the inflation rate but the currency depreciation that brought it about.  So, one has to begin by inventing a tool to measure currency depreciation.  Such an approach has been employed and a solution offered in A.L.M. Abdul Gafoor’s Commercial Banking in the presence of Inflation (1999) and interested readers are referred to the literature.

© Islamic Finance Today – Pioneer Publications (Pvt) Ltd
Post Disclaimer | Support Us

Support Us

The sailanmuslim.com web site  entirely supported by individual donors and well wishers. If you regularly visit this site and wish to show your appreciation, or if you wish to see further development of sailanmuslim.com, please donate us

IMPORTANT : All content hosted on sailanmuslim.com is solely for non-commercial purposes and with the permission of original copyright holders. Any other use of the hosted content, such as for financial gain, requires express approval from the copyright owners.

Afkham Azeez

I am a committer & Project Management Committee (PMC) member of the Apache Web Services project. I work as a software architect at WSO2 and am the Product Manager of WSO2 Web Services Application Server (WSAS). I also lead the WSO2 Carbon framework project. My areas of interest include distributed computing, SOA, Highly Available & Highly Scalable applications & J2EE technologies. My current research area is cloud computing and am currently trying to make Web services autoscale on Amazon EC2. I am the author of the clustering implementation for Apache Axis2. I hold a B.Sc. first class honors degree in Computer Science & Engineering from the University of Moratuwa, Sri Lanka, and am currently reading for a Masters Degree in Computer Science specializing in Software Architecture.

Related Articles

One Comment

  1. The Muslims have contributed a lot to demonstrate their love and affection of their mother land – Sri Lanka. These contributions are now conveniently forgotten by the Chauvanists in Todays Society.

    The Museum premises:

    It is said that the only pledge the philanthropist (I think it was Marhoom Sir Razik Fareed’s father or Grandfather) when he donated the building to the then Government of Ceylon that the Museum should be closed on Fridays. I am not sure whether it is still followed/ observed.

    The Gaffoor Building that stands majestically in the fort.

    According to hearsay it has been declared as a national treasure. I do not know whether any publicity was given to this effect by the government.

    The Clock Tower at the heart of Kandy Town donated by Ismail family.
    Very soon the plague seen on the tower may be removed.

    The Kattankudy Hospital (Now called Arayampathy District Hospital):

    The sprawling land area for this building was donated by a Muslim Philanthropist Aawanna Maana Cheena (The father of the late Mudaliyar Sinna Lebbe and the grand father of the late Latiff Sinna Lebbe and the great grandfather of the late Rizvie Sinna Lebbe – All three of them were MPs of Batticaloa Electorate). This plague was removed in the 70’s by the Tamil Tigers to hide the fact from the present and future generation. Older Honest Tamil brothers living in the area will bear witness to this.

    The Baticaloa Technical College (Formerly Carpentry Training Centre):

    This land too was donated by the late Mudaliyar Sinna Lebbe. I believe the plague to the effect should still be available. Soon this too may be removed.

    and

    There should be many more such worthwhile contributions by the Muslims of Sri Lanka in demonstration of their love and affection towards their country in general and all brother communities in particular.

    I appeal the Muslim Peace Secretariat to compile a list of donation of lands and buildings and other contributions made by the Muslims throughout Sri Lanka and publish it enabling the present and future generation of Muslims to know their forefathers’ contributions to their mother country.

    Further, in the city there is not a single decent place where poor Muslims coming here for medical treatment, interviews, etc from outstations could stay. Even though the Mosques here serve this purpose to some extent, the females and families find it extremely difficult to find a proper or at least a mediocre accommodation. What sprawling premises do we Muslims have in Colombo in the likes of Ramakrishna Mission in Wellawatte and Kathiresan Temple in Bambalapitiya?

    Muslim Organizations, please give some serious thought

    This story deserves a place in any book on ‘remarkable tales.’

    It is a story of an unusual journey of an elephant from a far flung jungle in the Eastern Province to the Dalada Maligawa, which finally ended up being given pride of place on a thousand rupee note still in circulation in our island nation.

    The elephant we are talking about is one many of us are already familiar – the pachyderm we have seen printed with a man wearing a cap near it, and appearing on the 1,000 rupees notes.

    The man appearing on the note is Umar Lebbai Panicker, a Muslim from the Eastern Province in Eravur, in the Batticaloa District, and the tusker on the note which was caught in 1925 in the Eravur forest, was reared by him.

    It is said Umar Lebbai Panicker presented this tusker to Dalada Maligawa and the tusker within a short period had escaped from there and went in search of him to Eravur. He had brought the tusker back again and handed it over to the Dalada Maligawa.

    The late President J.R. Jayewardene in order to recognize the long services of the tusker had declared it as a national asset in 1984. This tusker which was named Raja, played a most significant role at the Esala Parehera processions in Kandy for half a century, gaining both national and even international fame, honored, respected and loved by the nation as a whole.

    The government in power then decided to honor both the person who presented the tusker to the Dalada Maligawa and the elephant by printing their pictures on the rupees 1000 notes, which brought honor to the eastern village of Eravur as well.

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

Back to top button

Discover more from Sri lanka Muslims Web Portal

Subscribe now to keep reading and get access to the full archive.

Continue reading